From Fireside Stacks <[email protected]>
Subject Abundance That Works for Workers—and American Democracy
Date March 31, 2025 10:03 AM
  Links have been removed from this email. Learn more in the FAQ.
  Links have been removed from this email. Learn more in the FAQ.
View this post on the web at [link removed]

Today we’ve got two guest authors: Kate Andrias and Alexander Hertel-Fernandez, co-directors of the Columbia Labor Lab [ [link removed] ].
Kate is the Patricia D. and R. Paul Yetter Professor of Law at Columbia Law School, and a co-director of the Columbia Law School Center for Constitutional Governance. Previously, she served as associate counsel and special assistant to President Barack Obama and as chief of staff in the White House Counsel’s Office.
Alexander is an associate professor and vice dean at Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs. From 2021 to 2023, he served as a deputy assistant secretary in the Department of Labor and a senior fellow in the White House Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs. You can read more from him on Bluesky @awhf.bsky.social [ [link removed] ].
Ezra Klein argues in his recent op-ed [ [link removed] ] (and at greater length in his compelling new book [ [link removed] ]with Derek Thompson) that a central problem facing Democrats is the crisis of scarcity. According to Klein, the places where Democrats govern are unaffordable because rules and political cultures constrain production and provision of housing, public transit, childcare, clean energy, and other valuable goods and services—and ultimately hobble effective government. He contends we can solve the pressing problems facing Americans—and offer a retort to Elon Musk and Donald Trump—with a new policy and politics of “abundance.” Abundance, as Klein describes it, is a political movement of supply: Instead of focusing on the (re)distribution of scarce existing resources, politicians should focus on expanding supply.
We agree that abundance is a worthy goal for the progressive movement, as is the project of reforming government to ensure it is delivering goods quickly and effectively.
But in order to be effective, abundance policy must benefit and build power for working- and middle-class Americans rather than enriching and empowering concentrated economic interests and generating a populist backlash that undermines democracy.
In particular, as two scholars of labor and American political economy, we seek to highlight the role that unions—workers’ best instrument for building collective economic and political voice—can play in the abundance movement.
At present, proponents of abundance are divided in their views of organized labor. Klein acknowledges that unions are not necessarily opposed to an abundance agenda. For example, he has stressed that Pennsylvania Governor Josh Shapiro’s remarkably rapid rebuilding of I-95 used union labor, noting [ [link removed] ] “[t]here’s nothing about unions doing projects that means they can’t be done fast.” However, a number of other abundance proponents have suggested that unions and labor-related policies are obstacles to greater production [ [link removed] ], construction [ [link removed] ], and robust state capacity [ [link removed] ]. These critics argue that unions raise the costs of housing by insisting on the use of union labor for construction; oppose transitions to clean energy because of their representation of unionized workers in fossil fuel industries; and delay government action with bureaucratic processes that make it hard to hire and fire workers at will.
What is missing from the abundance debates thus far is a recognition of the positive role that unions can play as a partner in achieving abundance, as well as a reckoning with the trade-offs involved in weaking labor power in the pursuit of abundance.
Organized labor can advance abundance in several ways.
We draw attention to three here.
First, unions can facilitate faster construction on large-scale projects through the provision of skilled labor throughout a project. This function is critical as labor shortages are one important source of delays in construction. An evaluation [ [link removed] ] by the US Department of Labor found that the use of unionized labor helped to prevent shortages of skilled construction labor for New York City schools. More recently, during the labor shortages throughout the COVID-19 pandemic, unionized contractors reported [ [link removed] ] fewer issues in filling open specialized craft positions than nonunion contractors.
Second, unions can help create the political will for abundance by forming coalitions to lobby the government to expand production or construction. In states across [ [link removed] ] the country, building trade unions are helping to train their workers in construction for the clean energy transition, such as building and assembling wind turbines. In turn, those unions are joining [ [link removed] ] with climate advocates and clean energy firms to expand state targets for clean energy production. Fostering more of these joint coalitions could help unlock further production in other sectors, such as health care, childcare, or public transportation.
Third, engaging unions—and other civic organizations—in the process of crafting abundance policy can help ensure the efficacy and the democratic legitimacy of the projects. That is, when workers are at the table, the policy outputs are more likely to serve the needs of working people and to have political buy-in of diverse communities. One way to provide workers a seat at the table is through “tripartite” administrative structures that bring representatives of workers, employers, and the public together on councils or committees that help set policy and then implement it.
The tradition of tripartism in the United States is weaker than in other rich democracies, especially in Northern Europe. But where we have tried tripartism in this country, it has often produced better outcomes for all. During World War II, for example, the United States engaged [ [link removed] ] in wartime tripartite bargaining between unions, wartime supply manufacturers, and government through the National War Labor Board. The deals struck [ [link removed] ] between the actors ensured continuous wartime production around the clock with access to skilled labor, and enabled more labor peace than would have been present without the deals. They also buoyed union membership, which in turn helped increase the wages, benefits, and collective voice of workers, strengthening the economy and democracy during the postwar period. More recent examples underscore that when labor is involved in policymaking, it can contribute shop floor expertise that makes production of goods and services more efficient and effective. In one powerful example, unionized nurses were able to bring their expertise to speed up [ [link removed] ] implementation of health IT investments such as electronic health records relative to nonunion nurses.
What makes unions especially important vehicles for building participation into government decisions is their internally democratic structure. Unlike other civic groups that may be “bodiless heads [ [link removed] ]”—professional staffs with no mass constituency to hold them accountable—unions, by definition and by law, are democratically run membership organizations. At their best, they aggregate and represent the views of millions of workers. In this way, union involvement in the policy process increases the democratic legitimacy of the process, and avoids [ [link removed] ] the problem abundance proponents highlight of individual citizens or professional advocacy groups capturing and stymieing government decisions.
Unions' relationship to abundance is not monolithic.
The role that unions play in supporting an abundance agenda is likely to vary by sector and by the presence of unions with varying organizational cultures, structures, and incentives. We acknowledge the resistance to the clean energy transition, for example, among some unions representing traditional automobile [ [link removed] ] manufacturing workers and extractive [ [link removed] ] industry workers, as well as labor opposition to technological [ [link removed] ]automation and trade [ [link removed] ]. But that resistance comes in part from a history of policy that prioritized corporate profit over workers’ interests, facilitating [ [link removed] ] significant [ [link removed] ] capital flight and failing to ensure adequate job quality and replacement in the face of technological adoption. Such resistance can likely be mitigated by an abundance policy that does not make the same mistakes.
In addition, we anticipate that unions are more likely to be partners in an abundance agenda when they represent broader constituencies of workers across industries and occupations—and thus are more attuned to the costs of scarcity. With this in mind, we believe that the reforms proposed by some labor scholars and advocates, such as complementing [ [link removed] ] workplace bargaining with more sector- or region-based organizing and bargaining, could also help align unions with an abundance approach. This is especially true to the extent that stronger sectoral or regional organizing and bargaining approaches for the American labor movement could support more tripartite policymaking.
On net, the evidence suggests that unions can be important partners in securing more—and better—production of goods and services while also ensuring that the distribution of economic gains is shared equitably across workers and while giving working- and middle-class Americans a stronger political voice. This brings us to our last concern with the abundance framework.
Ultimately, the neglect of labor by those who urge abundance is indicative of a broader problem.
The discourse to date has often obscured the potential trade-offs involved between the abundance agenda and the health of the broader American political economy. Concerns about the distribution of income and wealth or the responsiveness of government to working-class citizens barely make an appearance in most abundance discussions. The focus instead is on growing aggregate wealth and supply.
Likewise, the failure of many abundance advocates to grapple with labor is indicative of a broader neglect of the political economy of policymaking—namely, the role that organized economic interests representing economic elites play in exploiting veto points across levels of governance and the ability of organized workers to serve as a countervailing force to that influence. More frequently, the focus of the abundance movement is on simply eliminating veto points—such as environmental reviews or public comment periods—rather than building representative, countervailing power that can channel the views of working-class Americans into the policy process.
Economic policy that ignores concerns about economic and political power threatens the health of a multiracial, egalitarian democracy.
It also is bad for abundance on its own terms. Any effort to expand production of scarce resources over a sustained period of time will require supportive political coalitions, of which labor can often play an important role. In contrast, if policymakers pursue an abundance agenda without attention to the economic and political voice of workers, they are more likely to produce [ [link removed] ] populist backlashes that undermine economic growth and democracy. Policies that create more jobs without regard to whether they are good jobs—or, worse, policies that suppress labor standards—are likely to leave important swaths of workers with grievances they may funnel into populist movements.
To be sure, additional research is needed to better inform policymakers’ understanding of the trade-offs and complementarities between labor and the abundance agenda and to help inform precisely how labor can best be engaged. For example, how might sectoral approaches explored [ [link removed] ] by an increasing number of localities and states be directed toward abundance aims? But the goal must be an abundance agenda that serves working people—not the economic and political elites who have already gained so much power over government. For that, we need to build in mechanisms for workers to exercise power over the policymaking process and to benefit from abundance projects.
If you ask Eleanor
“We had better remember that the gains of organized labor have been eventually the gains of all workers, and that they only have the power of numbers as opposed to the very great powers in the hands of industrial associations and organizations.”
- Eleanor Roosevelt, My Day (December 10, 1945)
Fireside Stacks is a weekly newsletter from Roosevelt Forward about progressive politics, policy, and economics. If you enjoyed this installment, consider sharing it [ [link removed] ] with your friends.

Unsubscribe [link removed]?
Screenshot of the email generated on import

Message Analysis

  • Sender: n/a
  • Political Party: n/a
  • Country: n/a
  • State/Locality: n/a
  • Office: n/a