Plus: Spring Statement, the cost of taxes and regulation, and killjoys
͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­͏     ­
Forwarded this email? Subscribe here for more

Time for a wealth tax?

Plus: Spring Statement, the cost of taxes and regulation, and killjoys

Institute of Economic Affairs and Kristian Niemietz
Mar 30
 
READ IN APP
 

In today’s newsletter:

  • Why wealth taxes won’t work

  • Nominal GDP targeting

  • Has the Chancellor done enough?

and more….


Wealth taxes used to be a fairly common form of taxation. In the mid-1990s, 12 OECD countries still had wealth taxes of one kind or another.

They have since fallen out of favour. All but three of those countries have since given up on them.

In recent months, though, the idea has experienced a major revival. Its most vocal proponent, the economist and former city trader Gary Stevenson, has built up a cult following around it. Of course, all the usual suspects from the Corbynite Left have also joined it.

As is often the case with these people, they show no interest whatsoever in how their ideas have turned out in practice so far: they only talk about them in the form of moral values and lofty ambitions. Even if they acknowledge that previous attempts to implement wealth taxes have been disappointing, these activists are convinced that next time will be different somehow.

But wealth taxes have been abandoned for good reason. Experience shows that they raise little revenue while imposing high administrative and compliance costs. Wealth has to be estimated with complex valuation methods, and these estimates have to be constantly revised.

Wealth taxes also lead to capital flight and suppress wealth formation, thereby eroding their own base over time.

However, in a stagnant economy with a housing affordability crisis, there will always be an audience for bad economic ideas. For free-marketeers, it is therefore not good enough to criticise wealth tax proposals in isolation. We also need to address the economic context which creates the demand for such proposals in the first place. Tough on bad economics, tough on the causes of bad economics.

Kristian Niemietz

Editorial Director


P.S. The best way to never miss out on IEA work, get access to exclusive content, and support our research and educational programmes is to become a paid IEA Insider. For a limited time only new paid subscribers will also receive a copy of Dr Steve Davies’ book Apocalypse Next: The Economics of Global Catastrophic Risks for free.

Welcome offer — 15% off for a year


IEA Podcast: Executive Director Tom Clougherty, Editorial Director Kristian Niemietz, and Director of Communications Callum Price discuss the Spring Statement, tariffs, steel, and wealth taxes, IEA YouTube


Sluggish growth demonstrates need for more fundamental reform

Responding to the Spring Statement, Tom Clougherty, Executive Director said:

“The Chancellor is right to cut spending rather than raise taxes again, and the cuts she has made are welcome. There is, nevertheless, a sense of unreality about all this. Policy is being determined by an arbitrary, moving target – a fiscal rule – rather than with any long term, principled strategy in mind.

“When you look at the sluggish growth forecasts, and the enormous liabilities the state will encounter as the population ages, Britain’s cycle of fiscal events feels a lot like rearranging the deck chairs on the Titanic.

“Turning increased defence spending into an exercise in ‘modern industrial strategy’ suggests that the government still has too state-centric a view of economic growth – one that is almost certain to disappoint in the long-run.

“Ultimately, we are going to need much more fundamental reform – going further and faster on the deregulatory, supply-side measures the government has begun to talk about; lifting the self-defeating burdens that have been imposed on business; and taking a long, hard look at what the state does and how it is funded.”

On housing regulation, Kristian Niemietz, Editorial Director said:

“While the Spring Statement was overshadowed by the bad news of downgraded growth forecasts, there are also some silver linings hidden in the OBR report which the Chancellor alluded to. In particular, the government’s planning reforms are projected to lead to a 0.5% increase in the housing stock by the end of this decade, which, in turn, is projected to lead to a 0.2% increase in GDP. 0.2% may not sound like much, but it is rather a lot if we bear in mind that this represents a pure gain, which comes at no cost and with no downsides. It is the equivalent of finding a pile of pound notes worth 0.2% of your annual salary lying around on the pavement: you would not feel like you had just won the lottery, but you would certainly pick them up.

“0.2% is just the direct, medium-term effect. The OBR also point out that if increased housebuilding leads to more people moving to high-productivity areas, the long-term growth effect would be higher still. This should raise the following question: if it is so easy to add 0.2% to GDP just with a fairly modest regulatory reform, why not repeat that exercise on a much bigger scale?”

On the welfare measures, Professor Len Shackleton, Editorial and Research Fellow said:

“The much-publicised benefit savings of £4.8 billion will be offset by extra spending on implementing this – more staff, presumably, to screen claimants. The problem is that the new spending is real while the savings are projections which may not be achieved, meaning the net savings of £3.4 billion may be fanciful.”

Responding to the statement, Julian Jessop, Economics Fellow said:

“This is not a ‘return to austerity’. The £14bn of savings on current spending is just a drop in the ocean: public sector current spending is still forecast to climb to £1,351bn in 2029-30, £219bn more than in 2024-25.“Moreover, most of the announced savings will come from efficiency gains in public services where productivity has lagged well behind, and from cutting some benefits paid to people who may not actually need them. Again, this is hardly ‘austerity’.

“Nonetheless, the late scramble to find additional savings on the welfare bill – simply to restore exactly £9.9bn of fiscal headroom – does raise the risk that some vulnerable people will lose out. Making such big decisions on the basis of spuriously precise forecasts is not a sensible approach.

“Indeed, the Spring Statement illustrates both the strengths and weaknesses of the UK’s current fiscal framework and the role of the OBR. On the plus side, the independent watchdog is reported to have rejected dubious costings produced by the government as recently as last week. However, this has prompted a last-minute rush to hit fiscal targets based on five-year forecasts which will almost inevitably be proved wrong.

“The room for error is also still incredibly limited. As the OBR itself has pointed out, the fiscal headroom is the third lowest any Chancellor has had against their rules, and could easily be wiped out by new shocks, including higher interest rates and a global trade war. There is no guarantee either that public sector productivity can catch up without fundamental reforms that will be resisted at every stage.

“There is therefore a high chance that the Chancellor will have to come back again with additional tax increases and more painful spending cuts as soon as the Autumn Budget.”

See the full analysis on IEA Insider:

Blog

Reflections on the Spring Statement

Institute of Economic Affairs and Tom Clougherty
·
Mar 26
Reflections on the Spring Statement

The Spring Statement was more-or-less as expected. A worsening economic outlook meant that the Chancellor’s headroom against her primary fiscal rule – a current budget surplus in five years’ time – had been wiped out and then some. As a result, budgeted spending was trimmed – notably on health-related benefits – and yet another crackdown on tax avoidanc…

Read full story

NEW PUBLICATION: Rethinking Monetary Policy

The case for adopting NGDP targeting in Britain

  • Inflation targeting fails to distinguish between demand and supply-side driven inflation, leading to suboptimal policy responses and delayed recovery from financial crises, such as the Covid-19 pandemic and 2008 financial crash.

  • Targeting the growth path of nominal GDP would provide a more stable macroeconomic environment, reduce policy uncertainty, and help to restore confidence in the Bank of England following post-Covid inflation.

  • The Government should consider updating the Bank of England’s mandate, replacing today’s inflation target with a new framework based on nominal GDP – or, in layman’s terms, total spending in the economy.

Read the Publication

  • Read author Damian Pudner’s piece in The Spectator

Watch communications Manager Reem Ibrahim discuss with Damian Pudner, IEA YouTube


News and Views


Analysis by Policy Engine for the Institute of Economic Affairs illustrated how the average cost of the coming tax rises on households will exceed £1,000 per year – and made the front page of the Daily Mail

Read the full analysis here:

Blog

New Analysis: the cost of tax hikes

Institute of Economic Affairs
·
Mar 29
New Analysis: the cost of tax hikes

By Nikhil Woodruff, Policy Engine

Read full story

Research by Public Policy Fellow Matthew Lesh was covered in The Spectator’s economics column ahead of the Spring Statement

“A serious rethink of Britain’s regulatory regime – in planning, digital technology, and crucially energy – could offer the kind of breakthrough Bailey believes only AI can deliver. Reeves won’t go there today, but she may soon find that a major pivot on regulation becomes impossible to avoid.”


Tom Clougherty made the case against retaliatory tariffs, BBC 5 Live


Reem Ibrahim was on BBC 2’s Politics Live ahead of the Spring Statement


Tom Clougherty criticised the Government’s stealth taxes, Daily Mail

“It is very dishonest to raise revenue in this way while claiming you will not raise taxes on working people”


Callum Price argued that the Government should be bold when it comes to Civil Service reform, The Telegraph

“Cutting the Civil Service even by as much as 100,000 would only take it to the level it was six years ago,” added Mr Price.

“The Government should consider Civil Service reform through this lens, and be bold. Growth is rightly the Government’s priority, and it is clear more officials does not equal more growth.

“[Sir Keir] Starmer and Reeves should shrink the size of the state and the Civil Service with it, and let business and the private sector drive the economy.”


Blog

Four Types of Killjoy: #1 Anti-smoking

Institute of Economic Affairs and Christopher Snowdon
·
Mar 27
Four Types of Killjoy: #1 Anti-smoking

In this series, the IEA’s Dr Christopher Snowdon explains the background and beliefs of the anti-smoking, anti-alcohol, anti-obesity and anti-gambling movements in the UK.

Read full story

Reem Ibrahim argues in that the Chancellor’s plan won’t touch the sides, Daily Express

“[W]orking people deserve to keep more of what they earn, rather than have it squandered by a bloated and inefficient state. The Government must go so much further in reducing public spending. We shouldn’t be trimming the fat, but instead be putting the Government on a high dose of ozempic.”


Blog

The Cost of Quantitative Tightening

Institute of Economic Affairs
·
Mar 25
The Cost of Quantitative Tightening

By the Rt Hon Sir John Redwood

Read full story

Insider is a reader-supported publication. To receive new posts and support our work, consider becoming a free or paid subscriber.

Upgrade to paid
A guest post by
Kristian Niemietz
Editorial Director and Head of Political Economy at the Institute of Economic Affairs. Views my own.
Subscribe to Kristian

You’re currently a free subscriber to Insider. For the full experience, upgrade your subscription.

Paid subscribers support the IEA's charitable mission and receive special invites to exclusive events, including the thought-provoking IEA Book Club.

We are offering all new subscribers a special offer. For a limited time only, you will receive 15% off and a complimentary copy of Dr Stephen Davies’ latest book, Apocalypse Next: The Economics of Global Catastrophic Risks.

Get 15% off for 1 year

 
Like
Comment
Restack
 

© 2025 Institute of Economic Affairs
2 Lord North St, London SW1P 3LB, United Kingdom
Unsubscribe

Get the appStart writing